Murmurings of disquiet in policy corridors
That the
current exchange rate regime in the market is not sustainable is beyond doubt
even for the policy makers in their private meditations. Just before he was
sworn-in, the new Minister of Finance boldly stated his intentions to phase out
the bond notes by December 2018. Just coming in from the private sector, he had
not carefully thought of the consequences of his emotional utterances, neither had
he mastered the art of differentiating policy statements from personal opinion.
And ever since those utterances, including his recent statements during the USA
trip that he would rather see the bond notes off sooner rather than later, the
bond note has taken a huge beating. It has nosedived 20% in two weeks.
The chasm widens
At a time when
banking deposits of about $6.5 billion were being thinly supported by official
nostro and cash balances below $300 million, the RBZ introduced bond notes in
November 2016. The motive was to physically monetise the chasm between
electronic balances and the real US$ in cash and nostro balances. The size,
extent and reach of the informal sector in Zimbabwe, compounded by the reality
that the majority of Zimbabweans live in rural areas with few electronic
payment platforms, created the urgent need to find physical money to support
the $6.5 billion deposits then floating in the market without nostro or cash
back-up. And the bond note was born!
Unfortunately
that chasm between the electronic monetary balances and the real nostro or US$
dollars supporting the same has continued to widen. With banking deposits now
sitting at about $9,5 billion and being supported by virtually nothing
meaningful in the nostros, the chasm is huge for a country whose current
account deficit has averaged $1.8 billion per annum since 2010. Although
officially the RTGS balances and bond notes are 1:1 with the US$, the market
realities have created huge premiums on the US$.
There is
abundant evidence that broad money supply is growing at an unsustainable rate. Driven
largely by fiscal excesses and equally culpable, a banking sector that has been
on lending overdrive, at its peak clocking loan-deposit ratios of 87% in 2011,
the stock of money is increasing much faster than GDP growth. For the past four years, cumulative GDP growth
has been only 7.8%, yet in just one year, broad money supply grew by 40.8% June
2018. This confirms that there is a significant amount of unproductive money
being generated in the economy which is not linked to productivity and that is
a source of instability on the asset and goods prices in the economy. In fact,
the continued depreciation of the exchange rate reflects this, probably the
reason why Prof Mthuli Ncube intended to announce his arrival with a fiscal
shock.
The sources of
broad money supply are, predictably, the usual suspects. Government debt
assumption alone for poorly run parastatals has injected over $2.3 billion into
the economy through issuance of TBs to creditors of RBZ, NRZ, ZISCO and CAAZ,
among others. On the other hand, significant treasury bills issuances to fund
the high budget deficits and the imprudent use of direct government overdraft
facility at the RBZ have all combined to create a liquidity swamp in the
economy.
Evidence is
everywhere that there are excessive amounts of unproductive money being
generated in the economy, and the performance of the banking industry provides some
insights. On the back of stagnating economy, declining loan to deposit ratios
and RBZ capped lending interest rates, the banking industry has surprisingly been
reporting amazing record profits! More than anything else, it’s a sign that
broad money supply is increasing unsustainably, and in real terms, the bankers
know very well their profits count for nothing and they will lose most of it to
inflation. History has taught us before, and Venezuelan banks can confirm it
now, that lenders lose value the most when inflation spikes. And the banking
sector in Zimbabwe knows it is now a moment of when, not how.
Bond notes are currency
The continued
growth of bond notes has created policy challenge, and options of phasing out
bond notes have been dominating policy utterances. The policy admission is that
the current exchange rate of 1:1 is not sustainable and is creating huge distortions
in the market, resulting in the RBZ assuming a pivotal role in the allocation
of foreign currency. These RBZ gymnastics have, undoubtedly, kept inflation at
bay. Inflation rate for August at 4.83% indeed confers a worthy gymnastic medal
to the RBZ in the face of such challenges. However, in its private
lamentations, the RBZ knows very well that this is not sustainable and a
solution to the fiscal excesses has to be found urgently.
Unfortunately phasing
out the bond notes by end of December, though possible, is not an option,
neither is it necessary. The fact that
virtually all bank deposits are only convertible for local purchases means, by
observation and deed, that the RTGS balances are already a local currency in
the electronic form, with the bond notes and coins being its physical
manifestation. No single depositors can
withdraw US$ from the bank at will or make international payments from their
bank balance unless they get allocated foreign currency under a special
arrangement from their bank.
This confirms, unambiguously, that the $9.5
billion deposits in the banking sector, though technically considered US$, are practically
electronic bond notes. To phase out bond notes therefore means phasing out all
the monetary balances in the economy and replacing them with some other
currency.
From the
strict sense and definition of currency, the bond notes are already another
currency within the current multiple-currency basket. There would, therefore,
be no logical reason to scrap it and replacing it with ‘own currency’ because
it is already our own currency!
The current
illusion that we have US$ as the anchor currency is confounding even the very
policy makers that are trying hard to believe it. One thing is certain though,
and its that sooner or later, the government will need to allow market forces
to determine the exchange rate. And that point will mark the confirmation or
crystallization of the loss of value for the RTGS balances that have, over the
years, been thought to be US$.
Rand
adoption – Catch me if can
The other
option to deal with bond notes as proposed would be the adoption of the Rand.
Granted, there are a lot of technicalities and conditionalities, but at the end
of the day, something has to happen to the $9.5 billion in banking deposits
today to be convertible to Rands. One certain outcome is that the $9.5 billion
deposits cannot be all convertible to Rands at the US$ market exchange rate
because our deposits they are not US$ in the practical sense. Therefore, only
that which is freely convertible, thus the nostro balances and US$ cash, will
only be able to be converted to Rands without loss of value. The rest of the monetary balances, thus about
$9.2 billion, can be convertible, but at a huge loss.
The previous
demonetization from the Zimbabwe dollar to the US$ in 2009 can give us a good
perspective into what can possibly happen when adopting the Rand. At the time
that demonetization was conducted in 2015, only US$$20million was set aside to
compensate all banking sector deposits as at 31 December 2008! The loss of
value was catastrophic to say the least. To imagine that the whole country,
including government, individuals, corporates and pension funds had money only to
the equivalent of US$20million as at 31 December 2008 is not an amusing joke.
Yet, when evaluated in the right context, it reflected the basic fact that the
government has no financial resources, in USD terms, to compensate the
depositors and therefore had to do with what was possibly available at the time.
Adopting the
Rand will suffer the same fate. The basic fact remains that the central
government has no foreign exchange reserves of its own to use in demonetizing
the $9.2 billion deposits in a way that will result in depositors preserving
the value of their money.
Therefore,
without any doubt, the adoption of the Rand will see massive value erosion on
the current stock of money in the economy. Of course options exist whereby
government can auction, to the highest bidder, its valuable assets such as Netone,
POSB, Agribank and so on to raise foreign currency to subsidise the
demonetization exercise to reduce the conversion losses. That said, one thing
that is definite is that such wholesale privatization will not be able to raise
$9.2 billion, even a tenth of it.
There are other
options such as securing external loans to fund the demonetization exercise. Still,
the fact remains that no financier would be willing to fork out $9.2 billion to
finance a demonetization process that, on its own, does not guarantee that the
adoption of the Rand will result in Zimbabwe generating surplus on the current
account in order to service this debt. In any case, the country already has
about $11 billion in outstanding external debt that has been long overdue. Therefore.
it is possible to adopt the Rand, but with consequences on loss of value to
depositors. Of course the deposits already do not have the value they purport
to have, but the wholesale conversion will precipitate and crystallise a steep
loss of value.
Loss of value – A fact of life
Whatever
currency regime the policy makers will opt to pursue, one fact remains still
that there is going to be loss of value on the stock of money in the economy for
others, whilst others will create immense wealth and savings.
The
government, which is the biggest borrower in the market with TBs of about $8
billion floating in the market, will be the biggest beneficiary of the currency
changeover or whatever will happen to the bond note. As the exchange rate
continues to depreciate, the real value of debt and indeed government
indebtedness will continue to fall. It would therefore be is in the best
interest of the government to see a real exchange rate that reflects the true
value of our local currency. This, inadvertently, whittles down the real value
of domestic debt.
Prof Mthuli
Ncube and his counterpart, George Guvamatanga, know pretty well that the
government has no capacity whatsoever to pursue a currency regime that will
obligate it to settle, in real USD value, its current domestic debt
obligations. Therefore, whatever currency regime the policy makers will settle
for, it will be one that recognizes that the current stock of money is not US$
and with that, loss of value will be crystallized for those with bank balances
whilst the borrowers will heave a huge sigh of relief.
Back to you, Mr President!
The President
has tackled many issues boldly since he assumed office, including the
prosecution of high profile corruption cases and appointment of newer blood in
ministerial positions. One issue sticking out as a sore thumb is the currency
issue. Bold decisions outside the politburo and central committee will need to
be made to tackle the currency issue. It will make him unpopular in the party
circles for a year or two, but in the fullness of time, he will be remembered
as having departed from the Mugabe rhetoric that put politics ahead of the
economy. In Mthuli Ncube and George Guvamatanga in the Finance Ministry, he has
a good pair of honest and pragmatic hands that can deliver the economic
stabilization program that eluded the previous administration for almost three
decades. And if he has to act, he has to do it now whilst still fresh with a 5
–year mandate before it too late.
Article first appeared in the Zimbabwe Independent on 28 September 2018
No comments:
Post a Comment